2. explain how sellers’ costs, producer surplus, and the supply curve are related.

In Consumer Surplus, it was explained how most consumers enjoy a surplus of benefits that exceeds the purchase price, which is called consumer surplus, equal to the price that they are willing to pay minus the price paid. Producers, likewise, also enjoy a surplus.

In a market of sellers, each will have their own cost of production. A producer is willing to produce a product if she can receive a price equal to or greater than the economic cost of producing it. Economic cost not only includes the cost of materials and labor, but also the opportunity cost of the seller's time. Hence, economic cost includes what economists call a normal profit.

Each seller has a different efficiency of producing a product. In a purely competitive market, however, producers are price takers, so they can only participate in the market if their economic cost does not exceed the market equilibrium price. However, because some producers are more efficient than others, they will make more than just the economic cost of their production. They will earn a producer surplus, equal to the sale price minus their economic cost of production.

Producer Surplus = Actual Sale Price – Economic Cost

No seller is willing to sell for less than his economic cost, and if a seller's economic cost = the selling price, then there is no producer surplus, so the seller is considered a marginal seller, indifferent to continuing to produce the product or doing something else. If the market price dropped, the marginal seller would be the first to leave the market to pursue better opportunities elsewhere.

2. explain how sellers’ costs, producer surplus, and the supply curve are related.

For instance, suppose you wanted to build 3 doghouses. Since you just bought the dogs, you want to get the dog houses built quickly. You hire 3 independent carpenters – John, Kelly, and Pete – to build 3 dog houses according to your specification. They decide to charge you $300 for each doghouse, for a total of $900. However, John's cost of production is actually only $100, Kelly's cost of production is $200, and Pete's cost of production is $300. Hence, John earns a producer surplus of $200, Kelly earns a producer surplus of $100, and Pete earns no producer surplus, so he is a marginal seller, because he is selling his service at his economic cost, where he is indifferent as to whether he gets the job or not. The total producer surplus of the 3 carpenters is $300, which can be seen from the graph below. As you can see from their supply curve, the producer surplus = the area bounded by the selling price and the supply curve of the 3 carpenters.

Because all sellers have some economic costs, no seller will sell for less than this, so the minimum cost of any product will equal the economic cost of the most efficient producer, so the supply curve begins with the most efficient producers, because they are the ones who can produce for the minimum price. As the market price increases, other sellers who are not as efficient will enter the market as long as the market price exceeds their economic cost of production. Note that the most efficient producers have a maximum producer surplus, while the marginal sellers have no producer surplus.

Economists use the concept of the willingness to sell that is comparable to the consumer's willingness to pay. Obviously sellers will be glad to sell their product for any price higher than their economic cost. Indeed, the higher the price, the greater their willingness to sell, but the market price is limited by what buyers are willing to pay. In fact, the producer surplus is limited by the market price, which is set by competition. So the producer surplus = the area under the market price above the supply curve.

How Does Producer Surplus Differ from Economic Rent?

When a supplier starts earning more than a normal profit, then that supplier is earning an economic profit, which is higher than the profit required to keep the supplier in the market. This excess profit is known as economic rent, and usually arises when competition is imperfect, such as in the formation of a monopoly or oligopoly.

What Is a Producer Surplus?

Producer surplus is the difference between how much a person would be willing to accept for a given quantity of a good versus how much they can receive by selling the good at the market price. The difference or surplus amount is the benefit the producer receives for selling the good in the market.

A producer surplus is generated by market prices in excess of the lowest price producers would otherwise be willing to accept for their goods. This may relate to Walras' law.

Key Takeaways

  • Producer surplus is the total amount that a producer benefits from producing and selling a quantity of a good at the market price.
  • The total revenue that a producer receives from selling their goods minus the marginal cost of production equals the producer surplus.
  • Producer surplus plus consumer surplus represents the total economic benefit to everyone in the market from participating in production and trade of the good.

Producer Surplus

Understanding Producer Surplus

A producer surplus is shown graphically below as the area above the producer's supply curve that it receives at the price point (P(i)), forming a triangular area on the graph. The producer’s sales revenue from selling Q(i) units of the good is represented as the area of the rectangle formed by the axes and the red lines, and is equal to the product of Q(i) times the price of each unit, P(i).

Because the supply curve represents the marginal cost of producing each unit of the good, the producer’s total cost of producing Q(i) units of the good is the sum of the marginal cost of each unit from 0 to Q(i) and is represented by the area of the triangle under the supply curve from 0 to Q(i).

Subtracting the producer’s total cost (the triangle under the supply curve) from his total revenue (the rectangle) shows the producer’s total benefit (or producer surplus) as the area of the triangle between P(i) and the supply curve.

The Formula for Producer Surplus Is:

Total revenue - marginal cost = producer surplus

The size of the producer surplus and its triangular depiction on the graph increases as the market price for the good increases, and decreases as the market price for the good decreases.

Image by Julie Bang © Investopedia 2019

Special Considerations

Producers would not sell products if they could not get at least the marginal cost to produce those products. The supply curve as depicted in the graph above represents the marginal cost curve for the producer.

From an economics standpoint, marginal cost includes opportunity cost. In essence, an opportunity cost is a cost of not doing something different, such as producing a separate item. The producer surplus is the difference between the price received for a product and the marginal cost to produce it.

Because marginal cost is low for the first units of the good produced, the producer gains the most from producing these units to sell at the market price. Each additional unit costs more to produce because more and more resources must be withdrawn from alternative uses, so the marginal cost increases and the net producer surplus for each additional unit is lower and lower.

Producer Surplus vs. Profit

Profit is a closely-related concept to producer surplus; however, they differ slightly. Economic profit takes revenues and subtracts both fixed and variable costs. Producer surplus, on the other hand, only takes off variable (marginal) costs.

Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus

A producer surplus combined with a consumer surplus equals overall economic surplus or the benefit provided by producers and consumers interacting in a free market as opposed to one with price controls or quotas. If a producer could price discriminate correctly, or charge every consumer the maximum price the consumer is willing to pay, then the producer could capture the entire economic surplus. In other words, producer surplus would equal overall economic surplus.

However, the existence of producer surplus does not mean there is an absence of a consumer surplus. The idea behind a free market that sets a price for a good is that both consumers and producers can benefit, with consumer surplus and producer surplus generating greater overall economic welfare. Market prices can change materially due to consumers, producers, a combination of the two, or other outside forces. As a result, profits and producer surplus may change materially due to market prices.

Producer Surplus Example

Say that there are 20 companies that make widgets, each producing them at slightly different costs. ranging from $2.50 to $3.50 per widget. In the market, there is an equilibrium point where the amount of widgets supplied meets demand at $3.00.

The producer surplus would define those producers who can make widgets for less than $3.00 (down to $2.50), while those whose costs are up to $3.50 will experience a loss instead. For the lowest-cost producer, they would enjoy a surplus of $0.50 per widget.

How Do You Measure Producer Surplus?

With supply and demand graphs used by economists, the producer surplus would be equal to the triangular area formed above the supply line over to the market price. It can be calculated as the total revenue less the marginal cost of production.

What Is Producer Surplus Simply Put?

Put simply, the producer surplus is the difference between the price that companies are willing to sell products for and the prices that they actually get for them. 

What Is Total Surplus?

Explain how sellers' costs, producer surplus, and the supply curve are related. The Sellers cost is how much they pay to obtain a good. The producers surplus is the amount they pay minus the cost of providing it. The supply curve measures this amount by looking at the area above the supply curve.

What is the relationship between the cost to sellers and the supply curve?

Economists generally lump together the quantities suppliers are willing to produce at each price into an equation called the supply curve. The higher the price, the more suppliers are likely to produce. Conversely, buyers tend to purchase more of a product the lower its price.
Producer surplus is a measure of producer welfare. It is shown graphically as the area above the supply curve and below the equilibrium price. Here the producer surplus is shown in gray. As the price increases, the incentive for producing more goods increases, thereby increasing the producer surplus.
The demand curve shows the buyers' willingness to pay at various quantities and prices. If the buyer's willingness to pay is more than the seller's price, the difference is the consumer surplus. For example, If an item costs $10 and you're willing to pay $12, your consumer surplus is $2.