The demand for Cheerios cereal is more price-elastic than the demand for cereals as a whole

Read Online (Free) relies on page scans, which are not currently available to screen readers. To access this article, please contact JSTOR User Support . We'll provide a PDF copy for your screen reader.

With a personal account, you can read up to 100 articles each month for free.

Get Started

Already have an account? Log in

Monthly Plan

  • Access everything in the JPASS collection
  • Read the full-text of every article
  • Download up to 10 article PDFs to save and keep
$19.50/month

Yearly Plan

  • Access everything in the JPASS collection
  • Read the full-text of every article
  • Download up to 120 article PDFs to save and keep
$199/year

Log in through your institution

Purchase a PDF

Purchase this article for $10.00 USD.

How does it work?

  1. Select the purchase option.
  2. Check out using a credit card or bank account with PayPal.
  3. Read your article online and download the PDF from your email or your account.

journal article

Measuring Market Power in the Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry

Econometrica

Vol. 69, No. 2 (Mar., 2001)

, pp. 307-342 (36 pages)

Published By: The Econometric Society

https://www.jstor.org/stable/2692234

Read and download

Log in through your school or library

Alternate access options

For independent researchers

Read Online

Read 100 articles/month free

Subscribe to JPASS

Unlimited reading + 10 downloads

Purchase article

$10.00 - Download now and later

Abstract

The ready-to-eat cereal industry is characterized by high concentration, high price-cost margins, large advertising-to-sales ratios, and numerous introductions of new products. Previous researchers have concluded that the ready-to-eat cereal industry is a classic example of an industry with nearly collusive pricing behavior and intense nonprice competition. This paper empirically examines this conclusion. In particular, I estimate price-cost margins, but more importantly I am able empirically to separate these margins into three sources: (i) that which is due to product differentiation; (ii) that which is due to multi-product firm pricing; and (iii) that due to potential price collusion. The results suggest that given the demand for different brands of cereal, the first two effects explain most of the observed price-cost margins. I conclude that prices in the industry are consistent with noncollusive pricing behavior, despite the high price-cost margins. Leading firms are able to maintain a portfolio of differentiated products and influence the perceived product quality. It is these two factors that lead to high price-cost margins.

Journal Information

Econometrica publishes original articles in all branches of economics - theoretical and empirical, abstract and applied, providing wide-ranging coverage across the subject area. It promotes studies that aim at the unification of the theoretical-quantitative and the empirical-quantitative approach to economic problems and that are penetrated by constructive and rigorous thinking. It explores a unique range of topics each year - from the frontier of theoretical developments in many new and important areas, to research on current and applied economic problems, to methodologically innovative, theoretical and applied studies in econometrics.

Publisher Information

The Econometric Society is an international society for the advancement of economic theory in its relation to statistics and mathematics.

Rights & Usage

This item is part of a JSTOR Collection.
For terms and use, please refer to our Terms and Conditions
Econometrica © 2001 The Econometric Society
Request Permissions

Markets

Demand
You will learn about:

  • the law of demand, individual and market demand, the demand curve
  • the factors affecting demand - price, income, population, tastes, prices of substitutes and complements, expected future prices
  • movements along the demand curve and shifts of the demand curve

You will learn to:
Examine economic issues

  • examine the forces in an economy that tend to cause prices to rise


Apply economic skills

  • graph a demand curve and predict the impact of an equilibrium
  • calculate the price elasticity of demand using the total outlay method

Traditional economics sets out some  basic premises. Let's think these through and see where they are happening in our everyday lives.

  • Demand is a function of price and consumers will generally buy less of an expensive product.
  • There are a variety of other factors that influence people's choices for consumption, e.g. income, population, tastes, prices of substitutes and complements, expected future prices. These factors cause the whole demand curve to shift left or right.
  • Consumers will not react to price changes in some products for particular reasons. This is referred to as inelastic demand.
  • Consumers will react immediately to price changes in some products for particular reasons. This is referred to as an elastic demand.
  • Inflation describes when the whole economy experiences price rises. Too much money in an economy causes inflation.

Breakfast Cereal- Choosing a Price

Reference: https://core-econ.org/the-economy/book/text/07.html#71-breakfast-cereal-choosing-a-price

To decide what price to charge, a firm needs information about demand: how much potential consumers are willing to pay for its product. Figure 7.3 shows the demand curve  (the curve that gives the quantity consumers will buy at each possible price). for Apple-Cinnamon Cheerios, a ready-to-eat breakfast cereal introduced by the company General Mills in 1989. In 1996, Jerry Hausman, an economist, used data on weekly sales of family breakfast cereals in US cities to estimate how the weekly quantity of cereal that customers in a typical city would wish to buy would vary with its price per pound (there are 2.2 pounds in 1 kg). For example, you can see from Figure 7.3 that if the price were $3, customers would demand 25,000 pounds of Apple-Cinnamon Cheerios. For most products, the lower the price, the more customers wish to buy.

The demand for Cheerios cereal is more price-elastic than the demand for cereals as a whole

The demand for Cheerios cereal is more price-elastic than the demand for cereals as a whole

Click on the link above to find out more.

The demand for Cheerios cereal is more price-elastic than the demand for cereals as a whole

Nerd Alert

​If you were the manager at General Mills, how would you choose the price for Apple-Cinnamon Cheerios in this city, and how many pounds of cereal would you produce?

You need to consider how the decision will affect your profits (the difference between sales revenue and production costs). Suppose that the unit cost (the cost of producing each pound) of Apple-Cinnamon Cheerios is $2. To maximize your profit, you should produce exactly the quantity you expect to sell, and no more. Then revenue, costs, and profit are given by:

                                             Total Costs        = Unit Cost X Quantity
                                                                               = 2 X Q
                                              Total Revenue = Price X Quantity
                                                                               = P X Q
                                                Profit                  = Total Revenue - Total Costs
                                                                               = (P X Q) - (2 X Q)

So we have a formula for profit:

                                               Profit=(P2)×Q
                                              

Using this formula, you could calculate the profit for any choice of price and quantity and draw the isoprofit curves, as in Figure 7.4. Just as indifference curves join points in a diagram that give the same level of utility, isoprofit curves join points that give the same level of total profit. We can think of the isoprofit curves as the firm’s indifference curves: the firm is indifferent between combinations of price and quantity that give you the same profit.

Want to know more? Head to this link to read and answer some demand-ing questions!

Can you bring a demand curve to life?

Are economists faking it until they make it?
You know it's there, when a price goes up you generally buy less of it and conversely, when a price goes down, you will go and buy more.
But it's hard to find a real demand curve. Listen to this podcast from Freakonomics and hear how Uber has provided economists with enough data to nail a demand curve down.

The demand for Cheerios cereal is more price-elastic than the demand for cereals as a whole

In your first assessment task you are researching factors around consumer's spending and saving patterns. This information will help you develop a rationale and move ahead with your research.

The demand for Cheerios cereal is more price-elastic than the demand for cereals as a whole

How does this all come together?

The demand for Cheerios cereal is more price-elastic than the demand for cereals as a whole

Price Elasticity - how quickly will consumers react when you change a price?

One of the critical elements of pricing is understanding what economists call price elasticity.
​Reference: 
https://hbr.org/2015/08/a-refresher-on-price-elasticity

The demand for Cheerios cereal is more price-elastic than the demand for cereals as a whole

The demand for Cheerios cereal is more price-elastic than the demand for cereals as a whole

What is price elasticity?
Most customers in most markets are sensitive to the price of a product or service, and the assumption is that more people will buy the product or service if it’s cheaper and less will buy it if it’s more expensive. But the phenomenon is more quantifiable than that, and price elasticity shows exactly how responsive customer demand is for a product based on its price. “Marketers need to understand how elastic, sensitive to fluctuations in price, or inelastic, largely ambivalent about price changes, their products are when contemplating how to set or change a price,” says Avery.
“Some products have a much more immediate and dramatic response to price changes, usually because they’re considered nice-to-have or non-essential, or because there are many substitutes available,” explains Avery. Take for example, beef. When the price dramatically increases, demand may go way down because people can easily substitute chicken or pork.

How is it calculated?

This is the formula for price elasticity of demand:
Price elasticity of demand  =

% change in Qdd                                                                       

% change in P

Let’s look at an example. Say that a clothing company raised the price of one of its coats from $100 to $120. The price increase is $120-$100/$100 or 20%. Now let’s say that the increase caused a decrease in the quantity sold from 1,000 coats to 900 coats. The percentage decrease in demand is -10%. Plugging those numbers into the formula, you’d get a price elasticity of demand of:

 -.10  

= -.5 or .5
                                                .20
Products and services can be:

  • Perfectly elastic where any very small change in price results in a very large change in the quantity demanded. Products that fall in this category are mostly “pure commodities,” says Avery. “There’s no brand, no product differentiation, and customers have no meaningful attachment to the product.”
  • Relatively elastic where small changes in price cause large changes in quantity demanded (the result of the formula is greater than 1). Beef, as discussed above, is an example of a product that is relatively elastic.
  • Unit elastic where any change in price is matched by an equal change in quantity (where the number is equal to 1).
  • Relatively inelastic where large changes in price cause small changes in demand (the number is less than 1). Gasoline is a good example here because most people need it, so even when prices go up, demand doesn’t change greatly. Also, “products with stronger brands tend to be more inelastic, which makes building brand equity a good investment,” says Avery.
  • Perfectly inelastic where the quantity demanded does not change when the price changes. Products in this category are things consumers absolutely need and there are no other options from which to obtain them. “We tend to see this only in cases where a firm has a monopoly on the demand. Even if I change my price, you still have to buy from me,” explains Avery.​

Is cereal elastic or inelastic?

Common examples of products with high elasticity are luxury items and consumer discretionary items, such as a brand of cereal or candy bars.

Which is likely to be more price

The demand for Cheerios cereal is more price-elastic than the demand for cereals as a whole. This is best explained by the fact that: A) Cheerios are a luxury. B) cereals are a necessity.

Why is cereal so elastic?

cereals are agricultural products. Agriculture productivity is seasonal in that there are times of bumper harvest as well as low harvest seasons due to varying conditions such as rainfall patterns . Therefore prices will be elastic due to the varying supply and demand levels of the cereals.

Which product is most likely to be price

China and glassware are most likely to be the most price elastic. The price elasticity of demand measures the demand for goods concerning the price. China and glassware have many substitutes in the market, and consumers will get attracted to those goods which are less expensive.