What is the term for a change in the price of an item leading to a small change in demand?

Elasticity of demand is an important variation on the concept of demand. Demand can be classified as elastic, inelastic or unitary.

An elastic demand is one in which the change in quantity demanded due to a change in price is large. An inelastic demand is one in which the change in quantity demanded due to a change in price is small.
The formula for computing elasticity of demand is:

(Q1 – Q2) / (Q1 + Q2)     
(P1 – P2) / (P1 + P2)

If the formula creates an absolute value greater than 1, the demand is elastic. In other words, quantity changes faster than price. If the value is less than 1, demand is inelastic. In other words, quantity changes slower than price. If the number is equal to 1, elasticity of demand is unitary. In other words, quantity changes at the same rate as price.

Elastic Demand

Elasticity of demand is illustrated in Figure 1. Note that a change in price results in a large change in quantity demanded. An example of products with an elastic demand is consumer durables. These are items that are purchased infrequently, like a washing machine or an automobile, and can be postponed if price rises. For example, automobile rebates have been very successful in increasing automobile sales by reducing price.

Close substitutes for a product affect the elasticity of demand. If another product can easily be substituted for your product, consumers will quickly switch to the other product if the price of your product rises or the price of the other product declines. For example, beef, pork and poultry are all meat products. The declining price of poultry in recent years has caused the consumption of poultry to increase, at the expense of beef and pork. So products with close substitutes tend to have elastic demand.

What is the term for a change in the price of an item leading to a small change in demand?

An example of computing elasticity of demand using the formula is shown in Example 1. When the price decreases from $10 per unit to $8 per unit, the quantity sold increases from 30 units to 50 units. The elasticity coefficient is 2.25.

What is the term for a change in the price of an item leading to a small change in demand?

Inelastic Demand

Inelastic demand is shown in Figure 2. Note that a change in price results in only a small change in quantity demanded. In other words, the quantity demanded is not very responsive to changes in price. Examples of this are necessities like food and fuel. Consumers will not reduce their food purchases if food prices rise, although there may be shifts in the types of food they purchase. Also, consumers will not greatly change their driving behavior if gasoline prices rise.

What is the term for a change in the price of an item leading to a small change in demand?

An example of computing inelasticity of demand using the formula above is shown in Example 2. When the price decreases from $12 to $6 (50%), the quantity of demand increases from 40 to only 50 (25%). The elasticity coefficient is .33.

What is the term for a change in the price of an item leading to a small change in demand?

This does not mean that the demand for an individual producer is inelastic. For example, a rise in the price of gasoline at all stations may not reduce gasoline sales significantly. However, a rise of an individual station’s price will significantly affect that station’s sales.

Unitary Elasticity

If the elasticity coefficient is equal to one, demand is unitarily elastic as shown in Figure 3. For example, a 10% quantity change divided by a 10% price change is one. This means that a 1% change in quantity occurs for every 1% change in price.

What is the term for a change in the price of an item leading to a small change in demand?

Don Hofstrand, retired extension value added agriculture specialist,

The law of demand states that as the price decreases, the quantity demanded increases, but does not say by how much. Demand elasticity is the change in quantity demanded per change in a demand determinant. Although there are several demand determinants, such as consumer preferences, the main determinant with which demand elasticity is measured is the change in price. Businesses are particularly interested in price elasticity, since it measures by how much total revenue changes with the price. A higher or lower price may result in more or less revenue depending on the elasticity of demand for a particular product. Demand elasticity can also determine how much a product or service is taxed, since a higher tax rate will result in higher revenue if the demand is inelastic or lower revenue if demand is elastic.

The price elasticity of demand = the percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in price.

Demand Quantity Change %
Price = ÷
Elasticity Price Change %

If a large change in price results in little change in the quantity demanded, then demand is inelastic. If a small change in price results in large changes in the quantity demanded, then demand is elastic. If the price change percentage is equal, though opposite, to the percentage change in quantity, then demand for the product is said to have unit elasticity.

Elasticity of Demand
If demand elasticity < 1 then demand is inelastic
= 1 unit elastic
> 1 elastic

Graphs of Perfectly Elastic and Perfectly Inelastic Demand

Perfectly Elastic Demand (Graph #1):

  • Elasticity = ∞.
  • Above price Pe, there is no demand.
  • At Pe, the market demand equals the quantity provided.
  • Below Pe, the market would also demand the quantity provided.
  • A perfectly elastic demand can be best illustrated by farmers selling corn in a competitive marketplace. No farmer can sell for more than the going price, since buyers can easily buy from their competitors. On the other hand, no farmers will sell for less, since they can sell all that they have for the going rate.

Perfectly Inelastic Demand (Graph #2):

  • Elasticity = 0
  • At quantity Qi, the market demands whatever is provided, regardless of the price.
  • The best real-world example of perfectly inelastic demand is a cancer drug that can cure a fatal cancer. Everyone with the cancer will want the drug regardless of price, and the drug company will provide whatever amount is demanded.

Although the elasticity of the product varies because of many factors, several factors are more important, including the necessity of the product, the availability of good substitutes, and the time period in which elasticity is measured.

Products with good substitutes tend to have a high elasticity of demand, since if the price increases, buyers can switch to a cheaper substitute. More closely related substitutes will have higher demand elasticities. Thus, margarine and butter are closely related enough so that increases in the price of either margarine or butter, will increase the demand for the other product. Meats, fruits, and vegetables are 3 categories of food in which, though not closely related, nonetheless, are close substitutes. So if the price of cantaloupes increases, then consumers may buy more watermelons or honeydew melons. If pork increases, then people may buy more ham, beef, or some other meat.

Related to close substitutes is how broadly the categories are defined — the broader the category, the less likely there will be close substitutes. So, the demand for a broad category such as food or clothing would be very inelastic, since people must eat or clothe themselves, while the demand for strawberries would be very elastic, since many other fruits can be chosen instead.

Another category of goods that would tend to be inelastic are complementary goods in which the demand is derived from the demand of another product. For instance, many different types of cars can be purchased, but once one is bought, then there will be demand for gasoline and oil, which have no close substitutes.

Since the elasticity of demand most often depends on being able to substitute one good for another, long-run elasticity will exceed short-run elasticity, because it will give people more time to find substitutes. For instance, when the price of gasoline increases, people will pay the increased price, since no substitutes exist for gasoline and people loathe changing their habits, such as by driving less. Over time, if gasoline remains expensive, then people will start buying more fuel-efficient vehicles or electric vehicles, lowering the demand for gasoline.

Demand Elasticity Comparison Over the Short Run and the Long Run

Inelastic Demand (Graph #1):

  • Over the short run, demand is more likely to be inelastic because of the limited options to compensate to changes in price. For instance, oil is inelastic over the short run, so when the OPEC countries decided to decrease supply, from Q1 to Q2, the price increased dramatically, rising from P1 to P2.
  • Note that the total revenue earned at price P2 = P2 × Q2, which is represented by the area bounded by P2 and Q2, and is larger than the area bounded by P1 and Q1.

Elastic Demand (Graph #2):

  • Over the long run, people have more time to compensate for changes in prices, so demand is more elastic. Continuing our oil example, people can buy more fuel-efficient vehicles, reducing demand for oil over the long run.
  • In the above graph, it is obvious that the total revenue earned at P2, represented by the rectangle bounded by P2 and Q2 is less than the original revenue earned at P1. Hence, more revenue was earned at P1, because the increase in price does not compensate for the decrease in quantity sold.

Calculating Price Elasticity of Demand

Since revenue is affected, businesses want to know how much the quantity will change with the changing price. Hence the price elasticity of demand is generally calculated by dividing the percentage change in quantity by the price change percentage. However, because price and demand are inversely related, the elasticity ratio will be negative, but since only the absolute value of the elasticity is considered important, the convention has been to show price elasticity as a positive number.

However, a problem arises when using a ratio of percentage changes, in that the actual percentage will depend on the initial price-demand point. For instance, if the price of cantaloupes drops from $4 to $2, that is a decrease of 50%. But if cantaloupe prices subsequently increases from $2 to $4, then that will be an increase of 100%, even though the absolute change in price is the same.

This problem is solved by adopting a midpoint convention, where the change in price or quantity is divided by the average of the 2 prices and quantities.

Midpoint Quantity = (Q1 + Q2) / 2

Midpoint Price = (P1 + P2) / 2

Price Elasticity of Demand Midpoint Formula
Demand (Q2 - Q1) / Midpoint Quantity
Price = ÷
Elasticity (P2 - P1) / Midpoint Price

So if the price of cantaloupes declines from $4 to $2 and the quantity sold increases from 50 to 100 cantaloupes, then calculating the elasticity using the midpoint convention will yield:

Elasticity (50 - 100) / 75 -50 / 75 -67%
of = ÷ = ÷ = ÷
Cantaloupes ($4 - $2) / $3 $2 / $3 67%
= Absolute Value of -1 = 1 = Unit Elasticity

Cross-Price Demand Elasticity

The cross-price elasticity of demand measures the change of 1 good by the % change in the price of another good, usually a close substitute. Here, the sign of the elasticity is more important, since it can be either positive or negative. When comparing close substitutes, the cross price elasticity of demand is generally positive, so if the price of bananas increases, the demand for other fruits will increase. If the compared products are complements, in which one is used with the other, then an increase in the price of one will decrease the quantity demanded of the other. So if the price of tennis rackets increases, then the demand for both tennis rackets and tennis balls will decline.

Elasticity of Other Demand Determinants

Although prices are the most important demand determinant, other determinants can affect the demand for a product, such as changes in consumers' preferences. One important demand determinant is income. The demand for normal goods increases with income. Although most goods are considered normal goods, some products are considered inferior products, where the demand for those products decreases as income increases. In other words, richer people buy better stuff. Income elasticity is generally measured with regard to normal goods, where the percentage change in demand quantity is divided by the percentage change in income.

Demand Quantity Change %
Income = ÷
Elasticity Income Change %

How Total Revenue Is Changed by the Price Elasticity of Demand

A business selling a product will want to know the price elasticity of demand for the product, since total revenue can be maximized by knowing the price elasticity of its demand.

Total Revenue = Price × Quantity Sold

When the price changes, the change in quantity sold may either increase or decrease the total revenue, depending on the elasticity of the product.

When demand is inelastic, total revenue changes in the same direction as prices, since the price change more than compensates for the change in quantity, which is represented by a steep demand curve. Hence, raising prices increases revenue.

Elastic demand is more sensitive to price, so small changes in price results in larger changes in quantities, changing revenue in the opposite direction to prices. Hence, increasing prices decreases revenue.

If revenue remains the same when prices change, then demand is considered unit elastic.

Example: The Interrelationship of Prices, Revenue, and Elasticity

Using the above example, total revenue for selling 50 cantaloupes at $4 apiece was $200. What happens to revenue if the price of cantaloupes is decreased from $4 to $2?

  • Demand is inelastic, if the quantity increases to 75 cantaloupes, yielding lesser revenue of 75 × 2 = $150.
  • Demand is unit elastic, if the quantity increases to 100 cantaloupes, yielding the same revenue of 100 × 2 = $200
  • Demand is elastic, if the quantity increases to 125 cantaloupes, yielding increased revenue of 125 × $2 = $250.

Because elasticity depends on percentage changes between 2 variables, elasticity will change depending on the 2 prices being compared, even if the demand curve is linear.

Elasticity, Revenue, and Exports

The relationship between demand elasticity and revenue is different for foreign sales, if the price changes are the result of changes in the foreign exchange rate between the domestic currency and the currency received from the foreign sales. If the foreign exchange rate changes, then the foreign price of the export will also change, and revenue in terms of the foreign currency will change in the same way as it would under a domestic currency, with higher prices leading to lower demand, and vice versa. However, the amount of revenue in domestic currency that the exporter receives for each of its products remains the same after the currency conversion. So, if the foreign price of the export drops, such as would occur when the domestic currency depreciates in relation to the foreign currency, then the quantity sold in the foreign market will increase, which will directly increase the revenue of the exporter regardless of the demand elasticity for the product. The opposite would occur if the foreign price increased, because the domestic currency appreciated.

How Foreign Exchange Rates and Demand Elasticity Affect Revenue from Export Sales

An American exporter exports American widgets to the UK. Now suppose that the exchange rate for American dollars ($) and British sterling pounds (£) is initially 1 to 1, or $1 = £1. Assume the following initial facts:

  • Initial exchange rate: $1 = £1
  • Quantity of American exports: 100 American widgets
  • Price of American widget in the UK: £200
  • Price received by exporter for each American widget: $200 (= £200 × $1/£1)
  • American exporter's revenue: $20,000 = $200 × £1/$1 ×100

Assume now that the US dollar has depreciated by 50%, so that $2 = £1, but the demand elasticity of the American export is 1, meaning that the quantity sold in Britain is doubled with a halving of price:

  • New exchange rate: $2 = £1
  • Elasticity of American export: 1 (unit elasticity)
  • Quantity of exports: 200 American widgets
    • (double because of the lower price in the UK)
  • New lower price of American widget in the UK: £100
  • Price received by exporter for each American widget: still $200 (= £100 × $2/£1)
  • American exporters revenue: $40,000 = British Price × Exchange Rate × Quantity = £100 × $2/£1 × 200

While depreciation of the currency certainly benefits exporters, whether or not it will benefit the country will depend on the elasticities of demand for both imports and exports. Many times, countries will try to increase their export revenue and increase the price of imports by depreciating the currency, with the hope of stimulating the domestic economy. Foreign exchange rates, and the elasticities of demand for imports in the domestic economy and for exports in the foreign countries will determine whether a depreciation of the currency will increase or decrease net exports, which is the difference between export revenue and import expenses:

Net Exports = Exports – Imports

The country will benefit from the depreciation of its currency, if the absolute value of the price elasticity of demand for exports plus the absolute value of the price of elasticity of demand for imports exceeds 1, which is called the Marshall-Lerner condition (MLC):


|PEDX| + |PEDM| > 1

  • |PEDX| = absolute value of the price elasticity of demand for exports
  • |PEDM| = absolute value of the price elasticity of demand for imports

If the Marshall Lerner condition is less than 1, then net exports will decline; if it equals 1, then net exports will remain unchanged.

What is the term for a change in the price of an item leading to a large change in demand?

Demand can be classified as elastic, inelastic or unitary. An elastic demand is one in which the change in quantity demanded due to a change in price is large. An inelastic demand is one in which the change in quantity demanded due to a change in price is small.

What is it called when a change in price creates a change in demand?

The proportion that quantity demanded changes relative to a change in price is known as the elasticity of demand and is related to the slope of the demand curve.

What is it called when price goes up and demand goes down?

Law of Demand. As we can see on the demand graph, there is an inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded. Economists call this the Law of Demand. If the price goes up, the quantity demanded goes down (but demand itself stays the same).

What is it called when a change in price either up or down leads to a relatively larger change in the quantity demanded?

Elastic. Referring to the situation in which a change in price either up or down leads to a relatively larger change in the quantity demand or the quantity supplied. Change in Quantity Demanded. A change in the amount of a product that consumers will buy because of the change in price. Microeconomics.