Which of the following elements of the constitution is the author defending in this quote?

Section 1

The executive Power shall be vested in a President of the United States of America.

He shall hold his Office during the Term of four Years, and, together with the Vice President, chosen for the same Term, be elected, as follows:

Each State shall appoint, in such Manner as the Legislature thereof may direct, a Number of Electors, equal to the whole Number of Senators and Representatives to which the State may be entitled in the Congress: but no Senator or Representative, or Person holding an Office of Trust or Profit under the United States, shall be appointed an Elector.

The Electors shall meet in their respective States, and vote by Ballot for two Persons, of whom one at least shall not be an Inhabitant of the same State with themselves. And they shall make a List of all the Persons voted for, and of the Number of Votes for each; which List they shall sign and certify, and transmit sealed to the Seat of the Government of the United States, directed to the President of the Senate. The President of the Senate shall, in the Presence of the Senate and House of Representatives, open all the Certificates, and the Votes shall then be counted. The Person having the greatest Number of Votes shall be the President, if such Number be a Majority of the whole Number of Electors appointed; and if there be more than one who have such Majority, and have an equal Number of Votes, then the House of Representatives shall immediately chuse by Ballot one of them for President; and if no Person have a Majority, then from the five highest on the List the said House shall in like Manner chuse the President. But in chusing the President, the Votes shall be taken by States, the Representation from each State having one Vote; A quorum for this Purpose shall consist of a Member or Members from two thirds of the States, and a Majority of all the States shall be necessary to a Choice. In every Case, after the Choice of the President, the Person having the greatest Number of Votes of the Electors shall be the Vice President. But if there should remain two or more who have equal Votes, the Senate shall chuse from them by Ballot the Vice President.

The Congress may determine the Time of chusing the Electors, and the Day on which they shall give their Votes; which Day shall be the same throughout the United States.

No Person except a natural born Citizen, or a Citizen of the United States, at the time of the Adoption of this Constitution, shall be eligible to the Office of President; neither shall any person be eligible to that Office who shall not have attained to the Age of thirty five Years, and been fourteen Years a Resident within the United States.

In Case of the Removal of the President from Office, or of his Death, Resignation, or Inability to discharge the Powers and Duties of the said Office, the Same shall devolve on the Vice President, and the Congress may by Law provide for the Case of Removal, Death, Resignation or Inability, both of the President and Vice President, declaring what Officer shall then act as President, and such Officer shall act accordingly, until the Disability be removed, or a President shall be elected.

The President shall, at stated Times, receive for his Services, a Compensation, which shall neither be increased nor diminished during the Period for which he shall have been elected, and he shall not receive within that Period any other Emolument from the United States, or any of them.

Before he enter on the Execution of his Office, he shall take the following Oath or Affirmation:--"I do solemnly swear (or affirm) that I will faithfully execute the Office of President of the United States, and will to the best of my Ability, preserve, protect and defend the Constitution of the United States."

It is commonly said that John Locke, the champion of social contract theory and natural rights, was one of the intellectual godfathers of the American Constitution. Yet for Locke and other social contract theorists, the major challenge was to figure out how ordinary individuals could form a state that allowed them to escape the uncertainties of living in the state of nature. The influence of natural rights theory is evident in many state constitutions, like the Massachusetts Constitution of 1780, whose explicit purpose is to form a stable order to protect “the natural rights” of its members. See Preamble, Massachusetts Constitution of 1780.

The formation of a national government is not intended primarily to secure a safe passage out of the state of nature, a task which should already have been successfully done by the states.  Rather it was to put into place a complex agreement among states that equitably distributes powers among coequal sovereigns. That second inquiry has little to do with the preservation of natural rights as such. The difficulty of undertaking this is reflected in the structure of Article I, which begins by defining the legislative power, and concludes in Section 10 by listing the prohibitions of activities that can be undertaken only by the states.

The confusion, however, only deepens because some of the most important provisions of Article I, Section 10, may address individual rights if they are understood, as Professor Rakove notes, as federal checks on what sovereign states are allowed to do to their citizens. In some of these cases, as with the adoption of ex post facto laws and bills of attainder, the concern is not with reserving to the national government certain tasks by denying them to the states. Article I, Section 9, Clause 3 prohibits the Congress from passing either bills of attainder or ex post facto laws, in the same fashion that Article I, Section 10, Clause 1 does for the states. The identical nature of the two prohibitions has nothing to do with the distribution of powers between levels of government and everything to do with the conviction that singling out certain people for special treatment, or imposing criminal punishments retroactively for actions that were legal when undertaken, reads very much like a natural law protection capable of universal application. Indeed, much of the debate at the Constitutional Convention was not about the propriety of these prohibitions, but about whether they were needed at all, given that the prohibited activities were universally condemned as odious in the natural law tradition. See Daniel Troy, Ex Post Facto, in The Heritage Guide to the Constitution.

One happy circumstance is that, for the most part, these two clauses have not played a central role in constitutional litigation. The same cannot be said of the Contracts Clause, which reads in part like a jurisdictional limitation and in part like a protection of the natural right to contract. The Clause itself was adopted from the earlier provision in the Northwest Ordinance of 1787, which provided: “It is understood and declared, that no law ought ever to be made, or have force in the said territory, that shall, in any manner whatever, interfere with or affect private contracts or engagements, bona fide, and without fraud, previously formed.”

One interpretive challenge asks which elements mentioned in the Northwest Ordinance carry over to the slimmed-down Contracts Clause, evidently written in more categorical terms. Part of the difficulty stems from the confusion over why the Framers included this Clause in the Constitution in the first place. One common explanation, offered by Professor Michael McConnell, is that it was intended to protect interstate contracts from assaults by state governments. See Michael W. McConnell, Contract Rights and Property Rights: A Case Study in the Relationship Between Individual Liberties and Constitutional Structure, 76 Cal. L. Rev. 267 (1988).

While true, it does not explain why the Clause applies to all local contracts as well. A second explanation, which McConnell also discussed, is directed toward local abuses such as debtor’s relief laws. Thus in speaking about Article I, Section 10 in The Federalist No. 44, James Madison denounced states’ “sudden changes and legislative interferences” in the business affairs of their citizens, even for transactions that take place wholly within one state.

The Northwest Ordinance of 1787 also raises more specific interpretive difficulties. The Ordinance only protected those contracts in place before the law went into effect, which was adopted for the Contracts Clause in Ogden v. Saunders (1827) over the dissents of both Justices Marshall and Story. The issue bristles with difficulties. One powerful objection to the Marshall/Story position is that it flies in the face of hundreds of years of legal history by refusing to give credit to statutes of limitations, recordation statutes, and the statute of frauds, all of which necessarily impair certain contracts that lack the requisite formalities in order to increase the security of exchange overall. But it hardly follows that the prospective reading of the Contracts Clause has to be rejected in order to accommodate these common-sense cases. In this regard, it is instructive to compare the Contracts Clause with the Takings Clause, where the latter allows for the taking of property for public use on payment of just compensation. Why not therefore read a just compensation exception into the Contracts Clause?

That position is not as far-fetched as it sounds. In West River Bridge Co. v. Dix (1848) the question was whether the United States could condemn a bridge that had been authorized by government charter. It had earlier been held that the Contracts Clause applied to government charters in Dartmouth College v. Woodward, (1819), in which New Hampshire simply sought to take over Dartmouth College, causing harm that could not be easily cured by paying compensation. But in Dix, it would have been absurd to say that no state could ever condemn any property for public use on payment of just compensation whenever that property had been acquired by contract, either from the state or from some private party. Hence the Court read in a just compensation exception that brought the Contracts Clause closer to the Takings Clause, again by a process of textual implication.

In an earlier work I articulated an intermediate position that first gives the Contracts Clause prospective effect, but then allows for statutes that meet a general just compensation test. See Richard A. Epstein, Toward a Revitalization of the Contract Clause, 51 U. Chi. L. Rev. 703 (1984). Thus, the additional security of transaction from the statutes of limitation and the like improve the lot of all individuals governed by them, so long as they do not selectively apply to benefit one group of individuals, say debtors, at the expense of others, say creditors.

That same position can apply to efforts to limit the remedies given for breach of existing contracts, as in United States Trust Co. of New York v. New Jersey (1977). In that case, the Court refused to let states eliminate bond covenants in loan agreements intended to prevent the diversion of cash to other purposes without also offering some substitute protection to the lenders. Adopting this approach for both prospective and retroactive changes of contract terms allows for a consistent application of the Contracts Clause to all contracts, and thus meets a major concern of both Marshall and Story: that a general law banning all future contracts would, under the majority opinion, escape any possibility of invalidation.

It is also clear that a just compensation exception is not the only one that has to be read into the Contracts Clause for it to make sense. Some contracts are formed by fraud or duress, and surely these common law defenses to their enforcement are not upset by the constitutional requirements. At the very least, that simple observation means that some version of the police power must be read into the Constitution to cover these eventualities. It was generally addressed in Brown v. Maryland (1827), which dealt with the import/export clause in Article I, Section 10, Clause 2, and recognized that “the police power” covered at the very least “the removal of gunpowder.” Brown gives rise in turn to the interpretive challenge of how to identify what forms of regulation survive the literal application of the Contracts Clause beyond the obvious cases of gunpowder and other potential nuisances.

It is on this issue that the difference between the classical liberal and progressive view is most vivid. The key case for these purposes is Home Building & Loan Ass’n v. Blaisdell (1934), which held that “emergency legislation” that allowed for the postponement of interest payments on a mortgage was not an impairment of contract because of the dodgy rationale that merely “modifying the remedy” does not necessarily impair the obligation of contract, even if the creditor is left worse off in consequence.

At this point the just compensation requirement in Dix is effectively eliminated in many cases of preexisting contracts. The upshot is that it leads to the adoption of a general “rational basis” test in contract cases—similar to that which the Supreme Court adopted with respect to other forms of retroactive legislation in connection with the Due Process Clause of the Fifth Amendment in Pension Benefit Guaranty Corp. v. R.A. Gray & Co. (1984) and the Takings Clause of that same Amendment in  Connolly v. Pension Benefit Guaranty Corp. (1986), as they applied to the federal government. The importance of this shift in connection with both the Contracts and the Takings Clause cannot be overestimated, given the huge shift in power from private parties to the national government.

For those, like myself, who believe in The Classical Liberal Constitution, this constitutional transformation energized huge political factions that, as Madison saw, worked against the interest of the public as a whole. In contrast, progressive thinkers tolerated the increased level of government activity. As Justice Thurgood Marshall wrote in Usery v. Turner Elkhorn Mining Co. (1976), virtually “all legislative Acts adjusting the burdens and benefits of economic life,” subject to a narrow exception for laws found “arbitrary and irrational,” fall within Congress’s authority. By implication the same level of deference was afforded to state legislatures. At this point, there is little distinctive left to the Contracts Clause, which is unwisely swallowed up by the general presumption in favor of all economic regulations.

Which of the following quotes from the US Constitution describes the requirements to be President?

No person except a natural born citizen, or a citizen of the United States, at the time of the adoption of this Constitution, shall be eligible to the office of President; neither shall any person be eligible to that office who shall not have attained to the age of thirty five years, and been fourteen Years a resident ...

What does Article 2 Section 2 of the Constitution mean?

The President shall be Commander in Chief of the Army and Navy of the United States, and of the Militia of the several States, when called into the actual Service of the United States; he may require the Opinion, in writing, of the principal Officer in each of the executive Departments, upon any Subject relating to the ...

What does Article 2 Section 1 of the Constitution mean?

Section 1 Function and Selection Clause 1 President's Role and Selection. The executive Power shall be vested in a President of the United States of America. He shall hold his Office during the Term of four Years, and, together with the Vice President, chosen for the same Term, be elected, as follows.

What does Article 2 Section 3 of the Constitution mean?

Article II, Section 3 both grants and constrains presidential power. This Section invests the President with the discretion to convene Congress on “extraordinary occasions,” a power that has been used to call the chambers to consider nominations, war, and emergency legislation.